The Economist---Revise and resubmit - 經濟

By Erin
at 2010-04-12T19:05
at 2010-04-12T19:05
Table of Contents
又要改版了 準備破財....
http://www.economist.com/business-finance/displaystory.cfm?story_id=15814840
Economics textbooks
Revise and resubmit
The crisis is changing how macroeconomics is taught
Mar 31st 2010 | From The Economist print edition
IN MORE than 30 years of teaching introductory macroeconomics, says Alan
Blinder of Princeton University, he has never seen interest as high as it was
last year. At Harvard, says David Laibson, students in his undergraduate
macroeconomics course are “chomping at the bit”. At elite American
universities, where endowments have shrivelled and hiring is down, increased
interest in economics is among the most benign of the recession’s effects.
Yet the crisis has also highlighted flaws in the existing macroeconomics
curriculum. Greg Mankiw, a Harvard economist and the author of a bestselling
textbook, points out that students can hardly be expected to make sense of
the crisis if they know virtually nothing about things like the role of
financial institutions. Yet if there is a “financial system” in most
introductory texts, Mr Blinder observes, it usually focuses on the demand and
supply functions for money. “The current curriculum fails to give students
even imperfect answers” to their legitimate questions about recent economic
events, he says.
Changes are coming. Mr Blinder is one of the authors of another popular
undergraduate textbook, which he is now revising. In the process, he is
having to think long and hard about how to balance the need for more detail
about things like finance with the constraints under which introductory
macroeconomic courses are taught. The new edition is likely to have a
prominent place for the idea of leverage and how it contributed to the
crisis. That is fairly simply explained. But some additional complexity will
be unavoidable.
For instance, the convenient fiction of a model of the economy with a single
interest rate was defensible as long as different rates moved in concert.
This, Mr Blinder says, is no longer something that students can be told “
with a straight face”. Some discussion of the role of securitisation and
systemic risk is essential, even if it feels like a lot of detail for
beginners to grasp. Mr Blinder, with a nod to Albert Einstein, says that
economists need to remember that things should be made as simple as possible,
but no simpler.
Revised textbooks will soon find their way into bookshops. Charles Jones of
Stanford University has put out an update of his textbook with two new
chapters designed to help students think through the crisis, and is now
working on incorporating these ideas into the body of the book. A new edition
of Mr Mankiw’s book should be out in about a year. And Mr Blinder’s
publishers aim to have his revised text on sale by June.
Courses in many leading universities are already being amended. Mr Laibson
says he has chosen to teach his course without leaning on any standard texts.
Francesco Giavazzi of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology is now
devoting about two-fifths of the semester’s classes to talking about how
things are different during a crisis, and how the effects of policy differ
when the economy hits boundaries like zero interest rates. Discussion of the
“liquidity trap”, in which standard easing of monetary policy may cease to
have any effect, had fallen out of vogue in undergraduate courses but seems
to be back with a vengeance. Asset-price bubbles are also gaining more
prominence.
Will these changes in the way macroeconomics is taught really stick? The
rewriting of widely used texts should ensure that some of the ideas that have
helped explain the crisis become part of the future curriculum. Mr Jones says
it will be instructive to compare the bestselling textbook in ten years’
time with the pre-crisis version of Mr Mankiw’s book. He thinks they will
differ substantially.
--
http://www.economist.com/business-finance/displaystory.cfm?story_id=15814840
Economics textbooks
Revise and resubmit
The crisis is changing how macroeconomics is taught
Mar 31st 2010 | From The Economist print edition
IN MORE than 30 years of teaching introductory macroeconomics, says Alan
Blinder of Princeton University, he has never seen interest as high as it was
last year. At Harvard, says David Laibson, students in his undergraduate
macroeconomics course are “chomping at the bit”. At elite American
universities, where endowments have shrivelled and hiring is down, increased
interest in economics is among the most benign of the recession’s effects.
Yet the crisis has also highlighted flaws in the existing macroeconomics
curriculum. Greg Mankiw, a Harvard economist and the author of a bestselling
textbook, points out that students can hardly be expected to make sense of
the crisis if they know virtually nothing about things like the role of
financial institutions. Yet if there is a “financial system” in most
introductory texts, Mr Blinder observes, it usually focuses on the demand and
supply functions for money. “The current curriculum fails to give students
even imperfect answers” to their legitimate questions about recent economic
events, he says.
Changes are coming. Mr Blinder is one of the authors of another popular
undergraduate textbook, which he is now revising. In the process, he is
having to think long and hard about how to balance the need for more detail
about things like finance with the constraints under which introductory
macroeconomic courses are taught. The new edition is likely to have a
prominent place for the idea of leverage and how it contributed to the
crisis. That is fairly simply explained. But some additional complexity will
be unavoidable.
For instance, the convenient fiction of a model of the economy with a single
interest rate was defensible as long as different rates moved in concert.
This, Mr Blinder says, is no longer something that students can be told “
with a straight face”. Some discussion of the role of securitisation and
systemic risk is essential, even if it feels like a lot of detail for
beginners to grasp. Mr Blinder, with a nod to Albert Einstein, says that
economists need to remember that things should be made as simple as possible,
but no simpler.
Revised textbooks will soon find their way into bookshops. Charles Jones of
Stanford University has put out an update of his textbook with two new
chapters designed to help students think through the crisis, and is now
working on incorporating these ideas into the body of the book. A new edition
of Mr Mankiw’s book should be out in about a year. And Mr Blinder’s
publishers aim to have his revised text on sale by June.
Courses in many leading universities are already being amended. Mr Laibson
says he has chosen to teach his course without leaning on any standard texts.
Francesco Giavazzi of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology is now
devoting about two-fifths of the semester’s classes to talking about how
things are different during a crisis, and how the effects of policy differ
when the economy hits boundaries like zero interest rates. Discussion of the
“liquidity trap”, in which standard easing of monetary policy may cease to
have any effect, had fallen out of vogue in undergraduate courses but seems
to be back with a vengeance. Asset-price bubbles are also gaining more
prominence.
Will these changes in the way macroeconomics is taught really stick? The
rewriting of widely used texts should ensure that some of the ideas that have
helped explain the crisis become part of the future curriculum. Mr Jones says
it will be instructive to compare the bestselling textbook in ten years’
time with the pre-crisis version of Mr Mankiw’s book. He thinks they will
differ substantially.
--
Tags:
經濟
All Comments
Related Posts
ECFA 大哉問! 請神手幫忙解答

By Selena
at 2010-04-12T17:27
at 2010-04-12T17:27
柏拉圖效率有什麼缺失?

By Iris
at 2010-04-11T20:49
at 2010-04-11T20:49
柏拉圖效率有什麼缺失?

By James
at 2010-04-11T19:17
at 2010-04-11T19:17
"專利權" 屬於哪種生產要素 ?

By Olivia
at 2010-04-11T18:59
at 2010-04-11T18:59
3月突見逆差 人民幣走勢成謎

By Caroline
at 2010-04-11T17:11
at 2010-04-11T17:11